Skip Nav

JLTP is currently transitioning articles from our previous website to this updated platform, with completion expected by fall 2024. We apologize for any temporary inconveniences this may present. Our commitment remains to deliver an enhanced user experience and the highest standard of content. Thank you for your patience and continued support.

X

Practical Pieces & Perspectives

March 22, 2017
Patent Transaction and Patent Financing in China: The Difficulties and Opportunities for Third-Party Service Providers
Runhua Wang

Dedication: Post-Doctoral Research Associate & J.S.D., University of Illinois College of Law.  I thank professor Thomas S. Ulen and Professor Jay P. Kesan for cultivating the ideas of this Paper, Carlos Delvasto Perdomo for his suggestions, and Zishu Wang and Samuel Branum for the editing.

 

I. Introduction

The Chinese government has strongly encouraged patent application and patent protection in the past decade.[1]  As a result, China contributed 89% of the worldwide growth in patent applications in 2014, whereas the United States contributed 6%.[2]  Statistics from the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) show that China has received the most patent applications since 2012 and that Chinese domestic patent applicants are filing more applications than applicants from any other country.[3]  This Paper introduces how third parties, referring to various types of patent service providers, are involved in the increasing patent market of China.

 

The WIPO statistics show that only a fraction of Chinese patents were filed abroad and that most of the patents only enrolled one foreign country, which indicates that the patents filed by China’s domestic applicants do not have a very wide geographical coverage.[4]  This may also imply that the average quality of Chinese patents is still low.[5]

 

Empirical evidence confirms this inference of low quality;[6] still, some scholars believe there is a trend of Chinese patent applicants improving the quality of the patents.[7]  This Paper discusses the difficulties, such as moral hazard, created by the different quality of patents in innovation commercialization, especially in patent transactions and patent financing, and how Chinese patent law exacerbates the difficulties.  The goal of this Paper is to encourage third parties to rethink their service for overcoming these difficulties.

 

Section II introduces the main categories of patent services provided in China.  Section III discusses the problems of the patent service and the paradox of promoting patent transaction and patent financing by policies and patent law.  Section IV suggests the opportunities for patent service providers in China.

 

II. Background: Service Map of the China Patent Market

Most patent applicants are represented by a registered patent agent when they apply for patents.[8]  Patent agents facilitate patent applicants by drafting patent applications and dealing with patent prosecution, such as conducting a prior-art search, drafting and filing patent applications, and answering examiners’ questions.[9]  As the number of patent applications increases in China, the demand for patent procurement also increases.[10]

 

The State Intellectual Property Office of the People’s Republic of China (SIPO) received 6.06 million (utility) patent applications from domestic applicants in 2016.[11]  The statistics by the All-China Patent Agents Association (ACPAA) show that China had 1,457 patent agencies and 14,795 patent agents in 2016.[12]  One patent agent deals with an average of eight new patent applications every month, which is much higher than the rates in the United States, Japan, and Korea,[13] which suggests an insufficient supply of patent procurement in China.[14]

 

At the same time that the number of patent agents has been increasing in China, the average level of their education has also been increasing.  In 2013, 29% of Chinese patent agents held a master’s degree and 3% of them held a Ph.D. degree.[15]  In the first-tier cities of China, such as Beijing, Shanghai, and Guangzhou, most patent agents held a master’s degree.[16]  Peking University Law School even established a graduate training program for patent agents.[17]

 

After patents are granted, they can be deployed to secure financing as intangible assets.[18]  For example, patentees can invest their patents for firm shares.[19]  Statistics by SIPO show that 34.3% of patents produced by universities are assigned to firms as investments in 2013.[20]

 

It is also common to use patents as collateral for loans in China.  Loans of 25.4 billion RMB were collateralized by patents in 2013 and increased to 48.9 billion RMB in 2014.[21]  Moreover, China’s patent market also provides patent insurance in more than fifty cities.[22]  Even though some international insurance carriers, such as AIG, IPISC, and Willis, have developed some mature patent insurance policies, the patent insurance policies provided in China do not exactly follow those carriers since patents are “jurisdiction-specific.”[23]  Two major types of patent insurance provided in the Chinese market are patent-infringement liability insurance for firms, as potential patent infringers, and patent-enforcement issuance for patentees.[24]  However, patent insurance has not been completely accepted by the market: the insurance coverage accumulated only 0.27 billion RMB between 2012 and mid-2015.[25]

 

Innovators expect monopoly rewards for their innovation.[26]  However, some scholars argue that innovators cannot be directly rewarded or compensated enough because their trade secrets related to the patents are more likely to be explored by their rivals through reverse engineering when they disclose the technology of the patents.[27] More scholars believe that innovators have strong perspectives on commercializing and improving their innovation after the monopoly rights exist.[28]  In addition to selling the patented products and generating revenue, licensing patents for expanding commercialization of products or co-inventing is also a critical measure that patentees use.[29]  Meanwhile, firms can license universities, public research institutes, or other firms for joint-R&D to share risks and profits, rather than independently develop technology.[30]  The statistics by SIPO show that smaller firms are more likely to license or transfer patents.[31]

 

There are patent agencies, such as CHOFN, and specialized patent transaction platforms that supervise patentees to transfer or license patents.  Gaohangip is the largest intellectual property transaction platform, which is like Amazon, where patentees can put their patents up for sale.  Patentees or Gaohangip lists the patents along with their prices, which are available to be searched by interested licensees for potential patent transactions.  Gaohangip functions as an agent and provides legal services for the patent transfer.

 

However, the statistics by SIPO show that in 2015 only 8.2% of patents were licensed by patentees and 5.2% patents were transferred,[32] suggesting an insufficiency in the business of patent transaction and patent transfers, as discussed in Section III.

 

III. Analysis
A. Difficulties for Patent Transaction

Out of the total firm patent owners surveyed, 62.1% believe that the major restriction of their profitability is that they cannot effectively prevent others from imitating the patents.[33]  On one hand, regardless of the arguments over the strength of patent protection in China, this relates to the low quality Chinese patents that are less competitive.  On the other hand, this concern suggests a mixed culture of copycat and innovation in China,[34] in which the competition increases as the follow-on innovation and downstream innovation raises in the market.  In this increasingly competitive market, moral hazard of patent transactions arises and grows too big to ignore because those licensed patents and any potential patents from the patentees are more likely to be circumvented.[35]

 

As a result, when the innovation ability of the licensees is high, patentees are less likely to transfer their valuable technology to avoid increased competition.[36]  Patentees may agree to transfer core technology only if the license includes a grant-back clause so that patentees are allowed to freely use further inventions by the licensees.[37]  However, given the low transaction rate, the moral hazard issues are not successfully mitigated in practice.

 

As a result, only 9.4% of the surveyed firms license patents or buy patents from domestic or foreign inventors.[38]  Out of the total number of firms surveyed, 19% invest R&D mainly in digesting the existing technology, while 54% invest R&D mainly in technology transformation.[39]  Even though firms are interested in purchasing technology instead of investing in learning, in this moral hazard scenario, licensing patents per se are not enough to learn core technologies from the patentee.  This is also a challenge for third parties to successfully bridge the parties in patent transactions when both sides do not have strong incentives to make a deal given the high cost of moral hazard.

 

While it is convenient to purchase and sell patents through an agency or a platform like Gaohangip, the agency or platform usually does not facilitate licensing.  Those agencies and platforms usually only facilitate drafting legal documents after parties enter into a patent transaction; they do not help with bargaining for the agreement.  Bridging the parties of patent transactions through those platforms with basic legal services effectively decreases the searching costs, but they cannot fill the moral hazard gap in patent transactions.

 

B. Difficulties for Patent Financing

Patent validity in China is stable: SIPO only received 3,724 invalidity petitions including utility patents, utility models, and design patents.[40]  With regard to litigation, the district courts in Shanghai decided 526 patent cases between 2002 and 2015.[41]  Only 15.97% of plaintiffs argued patent invalidity, while only 2.85% of third parties argued patent invalidity.[42]  Even though 20.7% of the plaintiffs in Beijing argued patent invalidity, for 487 patent cases between 2004 and 2015, only 2.04% patents were invalidated by courts.[43]

 

Nevertheless, this low invalidity rate does not provide patent owners strong incentives to purchase patent insurance.  They try to avoid litigation when they claim the insurance and when they do not have strong confidence in their patents’ validity.[44]

 

Therefore, the low patent invalidity rate does not mean a high quality of patents in China.  Indeed, lenders still hesitate to adopt patents per se as collateral.  Bank lenders usually ask for a loan guarantee in addition to patent collateral,[45] and they even prefer a combination of patent collateral, insurance, and guarantees to minimize risks.[46]  A loan guarantor in this circumstance is usually provided by the government or a government-funded mutual fund or incubator.[47]

 

Due to the high and complex thresholds, patent owners still have material difficulties in securing finance through loans.  The survey by SIPO shows that 45.3% of the firms that own patents rights complained about cash flow problems that can lead to a failure to finance patent commercialization.[48]  This could also be a result of the inevitable high cost of moral hazard in the loan market for patents.  Weak patent enforcement[49] in this litigation-averse society[50] exacerbates moral hazard issues.  These issues cannot even be mitigated by an emerging market of patent valuation in China, in which lenders can estimate patent value through economic analysis by patent valuation institutes.[51]

 

C. Paradoxes in Promoting Patent Transaction and Financing by Policies and Patent Law
1. Policies that Promote Patent Transaction and Patent Financing

In order to encourage patent applications and minimize the transaction costs in patent transactions and patent financing,[52] both the central government of China and the local governments have adopted various favorable policies for patent applicants, patent holders, and patent service providers,[53] such as the patent transaction platform—Shanghai United Assets and Equity Exchange.

 

Patent issuance in China was initiated by SIPO and the People’s Insurance Company of China (PICC).[54]  Meanwhile, local governments subsidize patent insurance to encourage the innovation firms to purchase the insurance.[55]  For patent collateralization, local governments actively provide interest subsidies or guaranties to facilitate innovative firms to acquire loans.[56]

 

The government also actively intervenes in patent applications and patent management by firms.  SIPO supervises local governments’ training for firms on patent management and patent strategies.[57]  Local governments provide subsidies and grants to fund firms to apply for patents and establish a patent management department.[58]  Many local governments also subsidize patent agents to improve the quality of patent applications.[59]

 

Most of the policies are enacted through economic instruments to decrease the transaction costs in patent applications, patent transactions, and patent financing.  However, even though the government can subsidize the application cost with SIPO, those current economic instruments cannot fully offset the cost of moral hazard that arises from the issues like low patent quality, weak patent enforcement, and the copycat culture.  Indeed, Chinese patent law is designed to prohibit patent transaction and patent financing to some degree.

 

2. Increased Cost in Patent Transaction and Financing by Patent Law

I am the first to argue that there are two main articles in Chinese patent law that could impede innovation commercialization, including patent transaction and financing.  First, Article 24 limits the scope of publication before the effective filing date of a claimed invention: the six-month grace period for novelty is only for the inventions that are disclosed in the exhibitions hosted or approved by the Chinese government, published at a specified academic or technological conference, or divulged by a person without consent by the applicant.

 

The exceptions of lack of novelty in 35 U.S.C. 102(b) regulating the one-year grace period does not restrict the manner of publications, including patentees’ sales and uses before the filing date, so inventors can test their market and consumers at an early stage.[60]  Moreover, Japan even has an Extensive Experimental Use Doctrine, which is not limited by a grace period, which helps with the understanding of the advanced technology and assisting with faster investing decisions.[61]

 

By contrast, Article 24 does not only provide a shorter term for inventors understanding the advancement of technology, but also does not provide a chance for inventors to test the market and consumers.  Therefore, it is not surprising to observe deficiencies in innovation commercialization in China.  Some patents may not have commercial value at all, but the law does not allow patentees to understand the practice before they file the applications.

 

Second, Article 69(2) defines broad prior user rights.  While western scholars often argue that trade secret owners should have relatively narrow prior user rights to promote innovation,[62] prior user rights are relatively broad in China.  “Prior” means the time prior to the patent filing date rather than the publication date or the beginning of the grace period as under U.S. patent law.[63]  The scope of “user” is also vague, which could suggest a person who has manufactured identical products, utilized identical methods, or is fully prepared to do so.  Article 69(2) does not mention a person who conducts an arm’s length sale or other arm’s length commercial transfer or uses with respect to the technology, which confuses many judges and legal scholars in China.[64]  Accordingly, Chinese patentees, most of whom are follow-on inventors rather than initial inventors, may be unwilling to enforce their patents since they do not know whether the infringers are excluded from patent infringement for prior user rights that may also threaten their patent validity for lack of novelty.[65]

 

Overall, these two articles include an underlying notion that patents should be filed at an early stage.  As the government provides many subsidies and grants to encourage patent applications, it is not surprising to observe a dramatic increase of patent applications and a strengthening mechanism of patent agencies in the recent years in China.  However, the law may also raise the cost of patent commercialization, patent transaction, and patent financing.  In this patent regime, it is hard to accurately estimate the patent value, so lenders cannot completely rely on patent valuation reports to adopt patents per se as collateral.  Firms also hesitate to license patents or conduct joint-R&D with potential licensees.

 

VI. Recommendation: Opportunities for Third Parties

The most solid business of patent service in China is patent procurement, which assists inventors in drafting and applying for patents.  Both the market demand and the government support are great in this area.  Even though the government heavily funds patent commercialization, patent transaction, and patent financing, the limited technology value, the culture of copycat and litigation-aversion, the strength of patent protection, and the design of some articles in patent law are the main barriers to conquer.  These barriers increase the cost of moral hazard in patent transactions and financing when the government instructs inventors to file more patents, and manage and commercialize their patents through subsidies and grants.  While there are agencies or platforms bridging patentees and potential buyers or licensees, the decrease in the transaction costs does not effectively eliminate the high cost of moral hazard when bargaining for an agreement.

 

Also, this cost cannot be reduced when the government directly or indirectly provides guaranties for patent loans.  These guaranties from third parties are used as substitutes for patent collateral rather than as supplementary to the patents.  Loans are offered for those guarantees or other financing packages in the name of patents, which shifts the risk burdens to those third parties.  Even though there are institutions evaluating patents’ economic value and even though SIPO provides patent evaluation reports for patents’ validity, lenders who ask for financing packages in addition to patent collateral do not completely rely on these reports.  Then, we cannot conclude that these reports are enough to eliminate the risks for those third parties.

 

V. Conclusion

Even though China has emerged as the country with the largest number of patent applications, there are material difficulties for Chinese patentees to commercialize, transfer, license, or finance their patents.  As the business of patent procurement and other supplementary service of patents grows, the market demands more third parties to fill in the gap effectively reducing the moral hazard to promote patent transaction and patent financing, such as promoting joint-R&D, facilitating inventors to improve patent quality, educating patentees to license their patents at an early stage, establishing reliable patent quality evaluation mechanisms, efficiently managing patent licenses, or monitoring the follow-on activities of licensees or patentee lenders.

Back
[1]

Shiwu Shiqi Woguo Zhishi Chanquan Shiye Da Fazhan (十五时期我国知识产权事业大发展) [The Career Development of Intellectual Property in the Tenth Five-Year Economic Plan] (July. 19, 2006), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/ztzl/qtzt/sywgh/hgyzw/201310/t20131029_872884.html.

[2]

WIPO, World Intellectual Property Indicators 23 (2014).

[3]

Id. at 7–8.

[4]

Id. at 14–15.

[5]

Dietmar Harhoff et al., Citations, Family Size, Opposition and the Value of Patent Rights, 32 Res. Pol’y 1343, 1343 (2003) (“Patents . . . representing large international patent families are particularly valuable.”).

[6]

Song Hefa & Li Zhenxing, Patent Quality and the Measuring Indicator System: Comparison Among China Provinces and Key Countries (IPSC Paper, 2014), https://www.law.berkeley.edu/files/Song_Hefa_IPSC_paper_2014.pdf.

[7]

Michael Li, Patent Quality in China, IPWatchdog (Mar. 27, 2014), http://www.ipwatchdog.com/2014/03/27/patent-quality-in-china/id=48720/.

[8]

Zhuanli Fa (专利法) [Patent Law] (promulgated by the Standing Comm. Nat’l People’s Cong., Mar. 12, 1984, effective April 1, 1985), art 19, (China).

[9]

Herbert F. Schwartz, Patent Law and Practice 7–21 (2nd ed. 1996).

[10]

Wang Suyuan (王素远), Zhuanli Daili Shichang Xuqiu Fenxi Shangpian (专利代理市场需求分析上篇) [The First Half Analyses of the Market Demand in the Market of Patent Agencies], 的博客 [IPRdaily] (Dec. 28, 2016), http://blog.sina.com.cn/s/blog_e0f474c10102wy1i.html.

[12]

Li Shulian (李淑蓮), Nianxin 15 Wan Renminbi Zhaobudaoren! Dalu Zhuanli Dailiren Quekou Da? (年薪15萬人民幣招不到人! 大陸專利代理人缺口大? ) [0.15 Million RMB Revenue But Failed in Recruitment! The Mainland China Has a Big Gap in Patent Agents?], Beimei Zhiquan Bao (北美智權報) [North Am. Intell. Prop. News] (Nov. 2, 2016), http://www.naipo.com/Portals/1/web_tw/Knowledge_Center/mainland/IPNC_161102_0801.htm.

[13]

Id.; see also Qingsheng, infra, note 16.

[14]

See Shulian, supra note 12.

[15]

SIPO, Zhongguo Zhuanli Daili Hangye Nianbao (中国专利代理行业年报) [The Annual Report of the Industry of Patent Agency in China] 10 (2014).

[16]

Miao Qingsheng (苗青盛), Sikao: Ruhe Chengwei Yige Youxiu De Zhuanli Dailiren (思考:如何成为一个优秀的专利代理人) [Thinking: How to Become a Great Patent Agent], Zhiren Wang (Apr. 22, 2015, 10:25 PM), http://www.wipren.com/html/2015/redian_0422/231.html.

[17]

Zhuanli Daili Zhuanye Fangxiang (专利代理专业方向) [The Major Direction of Patent Agency] (2015), http://www.law.pku.edu.cn/docs/2015-04/20150427171829618046.pdf.

[18]

See Richard Hall, A Framework Linking Intangible Resources and Capabilities to Sustainable Advantage, 14 Strategic Mgmt. J. 607 (1993).

[19]

Huang Pulin (黄璞琳), Gudong Nengfou Yi Zhuce Shangbiao Huo Zhuanli Shiyongquan Chuzi (股东能否以注册商标或专利使用权出资?) [Can Shareholders Use Registered Trademarks or Patent Rights to Invest in the Firm], Zhongguo Gongshang Bao (中国工商报) [China Industry & Com. News] (Aug. 24, 2015), http://www.saic.gov.cn/gsld/gztt/xxb/201508/t20150824_160956.html.

[20]

SIPO, Zhuanli Tongji Jianbao (专利统计简报) [Patent Statistic Bulletin] 2 (2014), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/tjxx/zltjjb/201509/P020150911515451537791.pdf.

[21]

Dingjian (丁坚), Zhongguo ZhongxiaoQiye Zhishi Chanquan Zhiya Rongzi Chengwei Yizhong Qushi (中国中小企业知识产权质押融资成为一种趋势) [A Trend of Intellectual Property Collateral by Small and Medium Sized Enterprises in China] (July 5, 2015), http://www.chinacpv.com/index.php/Home/Xinwendongtai/show/lx/gsxw/id/34.

[22]

Jili Chu, Recent Developments in Patent Insurance in China (Jan. 26, 2017), http://en.naipo.com/Portals/0/web_en/Knowledge_Center/Feature/IPNE_170126_0702.htm.

[23]

Id.

[24]

Wang Yu (王宇), Zhuanli Baoxian: Zhuqi Chuangxi Chuangye Baohu Weiqiang (专利保险:筑起创新创业保护围墙) [Patent Insurance: Structuring the Walls for Protecting Innovation and Entrepreneurship], Zhishi Chanquan Bao (知识产权报)[Intell. Prop. News] (Dec. 2, 2015), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/ztzl/qtzt/zscqzldzcywzcx/fxjd/201609/t20160901_1289578.html.

[25]

Id.

[26]

See Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & Econ. 265 (1977).

[27]

Fritz Machlup & Edith Penrose, The Patent Controversy in the Nineteenth Century, 10 J. Econ. History 1 (1950).

[28]

Mark A. Lemley, Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 129 (2004); see also Steven N. S. Cheung, Property Rights and Invention, in 8 Research in Law and Economics: The Economics of Patents and Copyrights 5, 18 (John P. Palmer & Richard O. Zerbe, Jr. eds., 1986).

[29]

Shubha Ghosh, Richard S. Gruner & Jay P. Kesan, Transactional Intellectual Property: From Startups to Public Companies 3 (3rd ed. 2015).

[30]

See Klaus Kultti, Tuomas Takalo & Juuso Toikka, Cross-Licensing and Collusive Behaviour, 23 Homo Oeconomicus 181 (2006), http://economics.mit.edu/files/5914.

[31]

SIPO, Zhongguo Zhuanli Diaocha Shuju Baogao (中国专利调查数据报告) [China Patent Data Research] 14 (2016), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/tjxx/yjcg/201607/P020160701584633098492.pdf.

[32]

Id. at 13.

[33]

Id. at 16.

[34]

Alexandra Harney, China’s Copycat Culture, N.Y. Times (Oct. 31, 2011, 11:37 PM), https://latitude.blogs.nytimes.com/2011/10/31/chinas-copycat-culture; see also Peter Guy, China Never Really Stopped Being a Copycat, and That’s Why Its Tech Companies Aren’t Changing the World, S. China Morning Post: Mind the Gap (Apr. 10, 2016, 10:00AM), http://www.scmp.com/business/article/1934779/china-never-really-stopped-being-copycat-and-thats-why-its-tech-companies.

[35]

See Jay Pil Choi, Technology Transfer with Moral Hazard (Discussion Paper Series No. 745, 1994–95).

[36]

See id.

[37]

See id.

[38]

See Kultti, Takalo & Toikka, supra note 30, at 6.

[39]

Id.

[40]

Tuwen Zhibo: 2015 Nian Faming Zhuanli Shenqing Shouquan Ji Qita Youguan Qingkuang Xinwen Fabu Hui (图文直播:2015年发明专利申请授权及其他有关情况新闻发布会) [Live of Pictures and Words: Press Conference About 2015 Invention Patent Application, Issuance, and Other Issues], SIPO (Jan. 14, 2016, 10:00 AM), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/twzb/2015ndzygztjsj/.

[41]

Gao Rongying (高荣英), Shanghaishi Zhuanli Qinquan Anjian Dashuju Fenxi Baogao (上海市专利侵权案件大数据分析报告) [Big Data Analysis of Shanghai Patent Infringement Cases] (2015), http://inews.ifeng.com/yidian/45985691/news.shtml?ch=ref_zbs_ydzx_news.

[42]

Id.

[43]

Gao Rongying (高荣英), Beijingshi Zhuanli Qinquan Anjian Shuju Fenxi Baogao Dashuju (北京市专利侵权案件数据分析报告大数据) [Big Data Analysis of Beijing Patent Infringement Cases] (2016), http://www.rensheng2.com/1120000/1110837.shtml.

[44]

Donghui Juan (董慧娟), Zhongguo Zhuanli Zhixing Baoxian De Zuixin Jinzhan Zhanghai Ji Duice (中国专利执行保险的最新进展、障碍及对策) [The Latest Progress, Obstacles, and Solutions for Enforcing Patent Insurance in China], in 7 Zhongguo Keji Luntan (中国科技论坛) [China Tech. Forum] 88, 91–92, (2015).

[45]

Guanyu Shangye Yinhang Zhishi Chanquan Zhiya Daikuan Yewu De Zhidao Yijian (关于商业银行知识产权质押贷款业务的指导意见) [Instruction Opinions on Loans with Intellectual Property Collaterals in Commercial Banks] (promulgated by China Banking Regulatory Comm’n, SIPO, St. Admin. for Industry & Commerce, Jan. 21, 2013) 2013 (China).

[46]

Zhuanli Diya Daikuan De Qingdao Moshi (专利抵押贷款的青岛模式) [The Qingdao Model of Patent Collateral for a Loan], http://www.haodai.com/zixun/97995.html (last visited Mar. 4, 2017).

[47]

Zhongguancun Guojia Zizhu Chuangxin Shifanqu Qiye Danbao Rongzi FuchiZijin Guanli Banfa (中关村国家自主创新示范区企业担保融资扶持资金管理办法) [Admission Methods of Zhongguan-Cun Since Park] (promulgated by Zhongguan-Cun Admin., effective Oct. 1, 2011) 2011 (China).

[48]

See Kultti, Takalo & Toikka, supra note 30, at 16.

[49]

See Ying Zhan, Problems of Enforcement of Patent Law in China and its Ongoing Fourth Amendment, 19 J. Intell. Prop. Rights 266 (2014).

[50]

See Bee Chen Goh, Remedies in Chinese Dispute Resolution, 13 Bond L.Rev. 1, 17 (2001); see also Guo-Ming Chen & William J. Starosta, Chinese Conflict Management and Resolution: Overview and Implications (Intercultural Commc’n Studies VII: 1 1997–98), http://digitalcommons.uri.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1015&context=com_facpubs; Cecilia Lai-Wan Chan, The Cultural Dilemmas in Dispute Resolution: The Chinese Experience (Presentation at the Conference of Enforcing Equal Opportunities in Hong Kong: An Evaluation of Conciliation and Other Enforcement Powers of the EOC, 2003), http://www.law.hku.hk/hrportal/wp-content/uploads/file/14062003a-CeciliaChan.pdf.

[51]

Liu Chunjie (刘春杰), Wang Fei (王菲) & Sun Haiyan (孙海燕), Zhuanli Jiazhi Pinggu Yanjiu Jinzhan (专利价值评估研究进展) [The Research Progress of Patent Valuation], 国知动态 [Guozhi Patent News] (2016), http://www.patentwarning.com.cn/content/details41_535.html.

[52]

Shiyiwu Shiqi Zhishi Chanquan Shiye Fazhan De Zongti Silu Mubiao He Zhidao Yuanze (“十一五”时期知识产权事业发展的总体思路、目标和指导原则) [The Overall Design, Goal, and Instructive Principles of the Development of Intellectual Property During the Eleventh Five-Year Economic Plan] (2006), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/ztzl/qtzt/sywgh/hgyzw/201310/t20131029_872883.html.

[53]

2016 Nian Quanguo Zhuanli Shiye Fazhan Zhanlue Tuijin Jihua (2016年全国专利事业发展战略推进计划) [The 2016 Plan of Strategically Promoting the Development of State’s Patent Development] (2016), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/gk/fzgh/201605/t20160516_1269421.html; see also Huang Yuanhui (黄远辉), Fuwu Shuangchuang Quanmian Dazao Zhishi Chanquan Yunying Shenzhen Moshi (服务双创,全面打造知识产权运营深圳模式) [Serving Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Completely Design the Shenzhen Model of Intellectual Property Deployment], http://www.sipo.gov.cn/ztzl/ndcs/zgzlznew/yypy/201611/t20161128_1303850.html (last visited Mar. 4, 2017).

[54]

See Yu supra note 24.

[55]

Chengdushi Keji Yu Zhuanli Baoxian Butie Zijin Guanli Zanxing Banfa (成都市科技与专利保险补贴资金管理暂行办法) [Temporary Methods of Administrating the Subsidies for Technology and Patent Insurance in Chengdu] (promulgated by Chengdu Municipal Finance Bureau & Chengdu Technology Bureau & Chengdu Intellectual Property Office, effective July 1, 2012) June 26, 2012 (China).

[56]

Xie Kaifei (谢开飞) & Xu Wenbin (徐文彬), Fujian Zhuanliquan Zhiya Rongzi Tupo 32 Yi (福建专利权质押融资突破32亿) [The Loans with Patent Collateral in Fujian Exceed 3.2 Billion RMB], Keji Ribao (科技日报) [Tech. Daily], Feb. 6, 2017, at 7, http://digitalpaper.stdaily.com/http_www.kjrb.com/kjrb/html/2017-02/06/content_361336.htm?div=-1.  Another example is the establishment of Zhongguan-Cun Credit Promotion Association.

[57]

Su Pin (苏品), Zhonguancun Zhuanli Daohang Gaoji Shiwu Xilie Peixun Zhi Zhuanli Bujue Chuji Shizhanban Chenggong Juban (中关村专利导航高级实务系列培训之专利布局初级实战班成功举办) [Zhongguan-Cun Patent Navigation and High Level Practice Training on Patent Geography Was Successfully Held] (2014), http://www.sipo.gov.cn/ztzl/ywzt/zldhsdgc/gjzldhcyfzsyq/201409/t20140915_1010102.html.

[58]

See Shanghai Shi Zhishi Chanquan Ju (上海市知识产权局) [Shanghai Intellectual Property Office], Shanghai Shi Zhuanli Zizhu Banfa (上海市专利资助办法) [The Methods of the Shanghai Patent Subsidies] (July 1, 2012) (China).

[59]

Id.

[60]

See Mark A. Lemley, Ready for Patenting, 96 B.U. L. Rev. 1171 (2016).

[61]

Kevin Iles, A Comparative Analysis of the Impact of Experimental Use Exemptions in Patent Law on Incentives to Innovate, 4 Nw. J. Tech. & Intell. Prop. 61 (2005); see also Jennifer A. Johnson, The Experimental Use Exception in Japan: A Model for U.S. Patent Law?, 12 Pac. Rim L. & Pol’y J. 499, 512 (2003); John A. Tessensohn, Reversal of Fortune—Pharmaceutical Experimental Use and Patent Infringement in Japan, 4 J. Int’l Legal Stud. 1, 25 (1998).

[62]

David H. Hollander, Jr., The First Inventor Defense: A Limited Prior User Right Finds Its Way Into US Patent Law, 30 Aipla Q.J. 37 (2002); see also Gary L. Griswold, Prior User Rights—A Necessary Part of A First-to-File System, 26 J. Marshall L. Rev. 567 (1993); Ning Lizhi & Li Guoqing, A Problem into American Prior User Rights System, 27 J. Nanjing U. Sci. & Tech. 1 (2014).

[63]

35 U.S.C. § 273(a)(2) (2012).

[64]

Wei Xiaoyun (韦晓云), Zhuanli Qinquan Zhong Xianyong Kangbianquan Wenti Yanjiu (专利侵权中先用权抗辩问题研究) [A Study of Prior User Rights Argument in Patent Infringement], 12 Renmin Sifa (人民司法) [People Judicature] 52 (2003).

[65]

He Huaiwen (何怀文), Jingwai Zaixian Zhuanli Shenqing Qike Zhunyong Dichu Shenqing Kangbian (境外在先专利申请岂可准用抵触申请抗辩) [Prior Use in Foreign Countries Cannot Argue for Prior User Rights], 109 Zhongguo Zhishi Chanquan (中国知识产权) [China Intell. Prop. Rights] (2016), http://www.cnipr.com/yysw/qqyd/201604/t20160408_196114.htm.

Sign Up Now